Bob
Have a question related to this hub?
Alice
Got something to say related to this hub?
Share it here.
Some political scientists use the effective number of parties as a diversity index. The measure as introduced by Laakso and Rein Taagepera (1979),[1] produces an adjusted number of political parties in a country's party system, weighted by their relative size. The measure is useful when comparing party systems across countries.[2]
A jurisdiction's party system can be measured by either:
The number of parties equals the effective number of parties only when all parties have equal strength. In any other case, the effective number of parties is smaller than the number of actual parties. The effective number of parties is a frequent operationalization for political fragmentation. Conversely, political concentration can be seen by the share of power held large political parties.[3]
Several common alternative methods are used to define the effective number of parties.[4] John K. Wildgen's index of "hyperfractionalization" accords special weight to small parties.[5] Juan Molinar's index gives special weight to the largest party.[6] Dunleavy and Boucek provide a useful critique of the Molinar index.[7]
Laakso and Taagepera (1979) were the first to define the effective number of parties using the following formula:
where n is the number of parties with at least one vote/seat and the square of each party's proportion of all votes or seats. This is also the formula for the inverse Simpson index, or the true diversity of order 2. This definition is still the most commonly used in political science.
This measure is equivalent to the Herfindahl–Hirschman index, used in economics; the Simpson diversity index in ecology; the inverse participation ratio (IPR) in physics; and the Rényi entropy of order in information theory.[8]
An alternative formula was proposed by Grigorii Golosov in 2010.[9]
which is equivalent – if we only consider parties with at least one vote/seat – to
Here, n is the number of parties, the square of each party's proportion of all votes or seats, and is the square of the largest party's proportion of all votes or seats.
The following table illustrates the difference between the values produced by the two formulas for eight hypothetical vote or seat constellations:
Constellation | Largest component, fractional share | Other components, fractional shares | N, Laakso-Taagepera | N, Golosov |
---|---|---|---|---|
A | 0.75 | 0.25 | 1.60 | 1.33 |
B | 0.75 | 0.1, 15 at 0.01 | 1.74 | 1.42 |
C | 0.55 | 0.45 | 1.98 | 1.82 |
D | 0.55 | 3 at 0.1, 15 at 0.01 | 2.99 | 2.24 |
E | 0.35 | 0.35, 0.3 | 2.99 | 2.90 |
F | 0.35 | 5 at 0.1, 15 at 0.01 | 5.75 | 4.49 |
G | 0.15 | 5 at 0.15, 0.1 | 6.90 | 6.89 |
H | 0.15 | 7 at 0.1, 15 at 0.01 | 10.64 | 11.85 |
The effective number of parties can be predicted with the seat product model[10][11] as , where M is the district magnitude and S is the assembly size.
For individual countries the values of effective number of number of parliamentary parties (ENPP) for the last available election is shown.[12] Some of the highest effective number of parties are in Brazil, Belgium, and Bosnia and Herzegovina. European Parliament has an even higher effective number of parties if national parties are considered, yet a much lower effective number of parties if political groups of the European Parliament are considered.